≡ Menu

Accounting Techniques in Korea: 18th Century Archival Samples from a Non-Profit Association in the Sinitic World

Seong Ho Jun ACADEMY OF KOREAN STUDIES
and
James B. Lewis UNIVERSITY OF OXFORD

ACCOUNTING TECHNIQUES IN KOREA: 18TH CENTURY ARCHIVAL SAMPLES FROM A NON-PROFIT ASSOCIATION IN THE SINITIC WORLD

Abstract: Little is known about pre-1900 East Asian accounting tech-niques. A double-entry method of accounting may date from the 1 1th century in Korea, but extant commercial ledgers are no older than 1854. However, extensive accounts of cooperative associations survive from the early 18th century. The Mun Clan Association accounts are examined to reveal their organizing principles and accuracy. The accounts demonstrate a highly accurate system that was intermediate between single-entry and double-entry accounting. While they are not from a commercial house, the accounts display sophisticated bookkeeping techniques designed to maximize rationality within a Confucian moral economy.

INTRODUCTION

In recent years, the Academy of Korean Studies (Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon)1 has gathered and published many private records and documents from post-1600 Korea, but there has been little research on these documents from the perspective of accounting and economic history. This paper examines a double-entry method used in the accounts (1741-1883) of the (Namp’yong) Mun Clan Association (MCA),2 an organization that is still active in Cholla Province. The MCA is representative

Acknowledgments: We are grateful to Anthony Hopwood and Elaine Tan of Oxford, the Korean Accounting Institute, two anonymous referees, and the editor for comments and suggestions that helped to improve the paper significantly. We also thank the Korea Research Foundation for supporting Seong Ho Jun’s research.

1 The Korean name was changed in February 2005 to Han’gukhak Chung’ang Yon’guwon, retaining the English name Academy of Korean Studies.
2 Please refer to the Glossary (Appendix A) for original script and characters.

of a major civil-society organization in pre-20th century Korea, the cooperative, mutual-aid society (kye).
Although a study in accounting history, the research on which this paper is based had roots in economic history. Information on commodity prices, labor costs, land and rental costs, and a number of other types of basic data have been collected in order to build models of Korean economic history. In the course of exploiting the data, decisions had to be made about their trustworthiness, leading to an analysis of the accounting principles at work. A high degree of sophistication and accuracy is evident, thus providing confidence in the quality of the extracted data [Jun and Lewis, 2005, 2006].

The MCA accounts were far more elaborate than simple, single-entry records. They reveal a complex linkage across sev-eral separate commodities used as currency, including unhulled rice, milled rice, and copper coin. Transactions in the ledgers were recorded in two different places. Many of the basic princi-ples of the double-entry method are apparent – personification of accounts, dual entry, integration, and periodicity. All the led-gers contain only real accounts; nominal accounts and profit-or-loss statements are absent. A concern for controlling losses is evident, while a corresponding lack of emphasis on profit-making reflects the dominant ethic, the Confucian “moral economy.” The paper features, in order, a literature review, a discussion of the moral economy concept, a description of the MCA ledgers, and a summary of the findings.

LITERATURE REVIEW

The Sinitic world of East Asia is the oldest, continuous civ-ilization on the planet, but very little is known of its accounting practices or economic history. However, accounting historians have attempted to address this lack of knowledge in recent years. Auyeung [2002, pp. 3, 5-7, 10-12; Auyeung and Ivory, 2003, pp. 9-12] offers an overview of traditional Chinese and Japanese accounting practices. There are a number of useful studies on accounting in China [Huh, 1979; Hsu, 1991; Gardel-la, 1992; Lin, 1992, 2003; Aiken and Lu, 1993, 1998; Chen, 1998; Gao and Handley-Schachler, 2003] and several on Japan [Nishi-kawa, 1956, 1977; McKinnon, 1994; Nisikawa, 1994; Someya, 1996]. There is at least one study on Korea [Yun, 1977]. It can be argued that most of these efforts suffer from insufficient detailed evidence to explain traditional usages before the adoption of western methods. An exception is Aiken and Lu [1998]. Many studies ignore historical or interpretative problems, though again, there are welcome exceptions [Gardella, 1992; Aiken and Lu, 1993, 1998; Chen, 1998; Auyeung, 2002; Auyeung and Ivory, 2003]. All previous studies are primarily concerned with governmental practices or commercial establishments.

Commercial activity in East Asia has a long history, but pre-modern Korean mercantile records are few. In fact, there are no known surviving commercial accounts dated earlier than the mid-19th century. Nevertheless, it is often asserted that Korean merchant houses in Kaesong City traded with China and Arabia and developed, as early as the mid-Koryo period (11th-13th centuries), a double-entry method known as the sagae Song-do chlbubop (four-sided Kaesong ledger method). Information on the system is available in Korean [Hyon, 1916; Hong, 1962; Kang, 1978; Yun, 1978, 1984; Cho, 2000], Japanese [Zensho, 1968; Yoshida, 1988,3 1999], and outlined in English [Yun, 1977]. The system is “four-sided” because it recorded the receiver’s name, the giver’s name, the commodity or cash received, and the commodity or cash disbursed. Fundamentally, the method required a dual entry for each transaction.

The four-sided method may have been centuries old, but direct evidence for it is more recent so that its “origins” remain a matter for speculation [Yoshida, 1988, pp. 147-150]. Yoshida [1988, pp. 137-140; 1999, p. 73] points out that all studies rely primarily on a few privately obtained account books, a 1916 accounting primer, and early 20th century ledgers (1898-1906) kept by the Taehan Ch’on’il Bank in Seoul.4 Yoshida [1999, p. 68] notes that some privately obtained account books held at the Kobe University Library concern a Kaesong merchant dating back to 1854. None of these documents can confirm the alleged mid-Koryo origins of the method. The 1916 primer and the ledgers from 1898-1906 have been analyzed in detail, but the older books are not well known and offer no direct evidence of a method in general use predating the opening of Korean ports to modern trade in 1876.

The 1916 primer deserves further explanation. By the late 19th and early 20th centuries, there was widespread disloca-tion as Korean society lurched headlong into the international market economy. Because the double-entry methods of the West had not yet penetrated Korean commerce and because there was general disarray in the Korean accounting world, a standard method was sorely needed.5 In 1916, Hyon consulted with two Kaesong merchants and authored a primer describing their four-sided ledger method. Hyon’s primer outlines an indigenous, double-entry method in which he defines terms and offers examples. There are modern elements in the primer, such as the use of Japanese terms [Yoshida, 1988, p. 139], the use of yen and zeni (Japanese monetary denominations), and the use of the zero as a place marker. Moreover, the question of Chinese influence deserves consideration. The presentation of accounts on the pages of the 19th century Korean commercial ledgers is similar to the style in the illustrations that accompany this paper. Because entries are not made in a similar fashion to Chinese entries with a single page divided into top and bottom [Ai-ken and Lu, 1998, pp. 228, 232], and because the terminology is completely different, it seems that the Korean methods were not derived from Chinese accounting. Nevertheless, there are striking similarities to the Chinese Lóngmén bookkeeping system, a prime topic for future investigation.

Although we have Hyon’s exposition of this indigenous practice, the problem remains that there are few available specimens of accounts that predate the 1850s that can confirm the general use of the method. Zensho [1968, p. 119] reports that, in 1921, when he was conducting a study of Korean accounting for the Japanese colonial authorities, he saw account books in a library in Kaesong City dating from the 1770s that used a four-sided ledger method, but he was only able to obtain books from the Guanxu period (1875-1908) for his personal collection and analysis. In addition, a North Korean researcher [Hong, 1962] has investigated accounts from at least 1798, which are part of the Kaesong City Museum archives [Hong, 1962, p. 58; Yoshida, 1988, p. 155, note 44]. Hong [1962, pp. 54, 59] also refers to accounts from the early 1820s in the Kaesong University of Politics and Economics (Songdo Chongch’i Kyongje Taehak). These account books may still be extant in Kaesong (presently in North Korea), but it has not yet been possible to gain access, much less to verify their existence.
The extant accounts of commercial and banking organizations from the mid-to-late 19th century are reputed to be based on a dual-entry system, but Yoshida [1999, p. 72] merely says that the 1854 debit and credit ledgers in Kobe University Library are “sister ledgers” (shimai chobo) and that they alternately record debits and credits for the same period. Yoshida does not supply sufficient detail to confirm the method used, and we have not been able to examine these books ourselves. While there are questions about the principles underlying the system, the current understanding is represented by Hong [1962, pp. 57-58], Zensho [1968, p. 119], Kang [1978, p. 89], Yun [1978, p. 99, 1984, p. i], and Yi [2001, p. 3], who argue that the four-sided ledger system is comparable to the Venetian “double-entry” system, is possibly older, and perhaps even more elegant.

On the other hand, Cho [2000, pp. 300-302] argues that the extant materials do not justify describing the system as double entry. He doubts that such a sophisticated system was possible in East Asia where Arabic numerals were not used and the Chinese script lacked the zero. Yoshida withholds judgment on the principles at work and objects to Korean claims to the “world’s oldest double-entry method” when based on evidence no older than 1854.

Promoters of such claims often link their assertions to de-velopmental economic models arguing for the indigenous ap-pearance of capitalism in Korea [Hong, 1962, pp. 50, 54-57]. Yoshida [1999, p. 74] correctly criticizes the conflation of a supposedly medieval dual-entry method with arguments about the early appearance of capitalism in Korea. Linking sophisticated accounting systems in East Asia to capitalism, something that is ill-defined at best for these different historical and social orders, does no more than echo the host of 19th and 20th century claims for European exceptionalism in developing capitalism based on double-entry accounting [Weber, 1927, p. 275; Spengler, 1928, p. 490; Braudel, 1983, p. 573; Gardella, 1992, pp. 317-319].

Nevertheless, the system described in Hyon’s 1916 primer and the practices that appear in surviving ledgers certainly present us with a number of questions about accounting method. In this paper, we will not discuss the method outlined in Hyon’s primer because there is the possibility that it was influenced by Japanese systems and does not reflect traditional methods. In order to confirm the existence of an indigenous Korean system and to ascertain its principles, it is necessary to identify older examples from various organizations, both commercial institutions and non-commercial establishments. This paper examines a case that clearly predates direct Korean contact with the West or with the West as mediated by Japan from 1876.

The ledgers of the MCA represent some of the oldest ac-counting books available. They are the accounting records of a non-profit, cooperative association. The shared terminology be-tween Hyon’s 1916 text, the MCA ledgers, and other similar material also recently made available6 is striking and suggests the widespread use of a traditional style of accounting. The pre-dominance of the accounts of non-profit organizations corrob-orates qualitative information on the general attitudes of pre-20th century Koreans. Merchant houses were socially inferior and treated with suspicion. By contrast, cooperative, non-profit organizations were socially acceptable, commonplace, and free of government control. Their accounts have been carefully preserved for centuries.

MORAL ECONOMY

The dynamic between accounting methods and the political and socio-economic environment has been explored by Loft [1986], Hopwood [1987], Hopwood and Miller [1994], and others for Britain, and by Aiken and Lu [1993, 1998], Chen [1998], Bloom and Solotko [2003], and others for China. The notion that accounting methods are merely an inert technology is quite defunct. In pre-1876 Korea, the prejudice against commercial activities and the social acceptance of ubiquitous cooperative associations were aspects of a socio-economic ethic that we refer to as the “moral economy” of pre-modern Korea. Our purpose in this paper is to analyze an indigenous Korean, double-entry method, not to offer deterministic cultural explanations for its use. However, we find that the concept of moral economy is useful in explaining significant parts of the content of the accounts presented below and of the method applied. We cannot yet show how the method shaped organizational and societal change since our sample is too narrow, but we can show how the method clearly responded to societal concerns.

6 There are similar data available from the Haenam Yun clan (1846-1882), also from Cholla Province, and from the Yongsan Sowon (Yongsan Academy,
1700-1705) in Kyongsang Province. For the Haenam Yun clan, see Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon (ed.) [no date], library microfilm no. 35-003212 and no. 35-003213. For the Yongsan Sowon, see Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa
Yon’guwon (ed.) [2000, pp. 721-809].

7 Clan account books in China have been mined as rich sources for the history of prices but not yet analyzed for their accounting method. For example, rice
prices from clan records for 1684 to 1802 have been published by Tanaka [1986].

Many scholars have outlined moral economies in other historical settings [Polyani, 1944; Wolf, 1969; Scott, 1976; North, 1977; Popkin, 1979; Thompson, 1993], but few have examined the concept’s applicability to China, much less Korea. Certainly, in Korea (and northeast China), the dominant moral ethic (Confucianism) was an ideological construction that fit an agricultural economy as practiced in a volatile ecological zone plagued by severe winters and devastating summer flooding. Unlike the north China plain, Korea is very mountainous and had no comprehensive state-run irrigation works, so a “hydraulic society” with extensive centralized powers did not arise [Wittfogel, 1957]. The political philosophy of Confucianism, particularly the Neo-Confucianism that appeared from the 13th century, was the systematic exposition of a moral economy and was well suited to Korean environmental constraints. It preached a social contract of localized mutual interdependence, ultimate government responsibility for subsistence, and interpersonal relations based on sincerity and clarity with fair and accurate accounting in transactions. These are a few of the practical reasons why Confucianism excoriated commerce. Gao and Handley-Schachler [2003, pp. 49-50] point out the overlap between Confucianism and Buddhism in their distrust of the profit motive. To a Confucian, profit pitted individuals against the collective. To a Buddhist, profit led to the illusion of material desire and the perpetuation of suffering. Of course, such normative principles did not preclude a concern with cost and profit in production [Ji, 2003]; yet, the pursuit of profit was a stigmatized activity.

Indications of the concerns and practices of a Confucian moral economy can be glimpsed in the MCA accounts – relief for economically weaker members, insurance for all, and no apparent concern with profit. In other words, the 18th century context for the books examined below is one in which local society was deeply imbued with cooperative principles, nearly every individual was part of a web of cooperatives, and com-merce was a socially despised activity. However, the disparagement of commercial activities did not mean the absence of rational, accurate accounting. Non-commercial, non-governmental institutions were commonplace, and many of these were organizationally complex and concerned with maintaining, expanding, and bequeathing corporate assets.

To determine what accounting system was in general use in Korea or even what passed for rationality in connection with economic matters, it makes little sense to focus on fringe activities practiced by commercial organizations that operated

60 Accounting Historians Journal, June 2006
from socially inferior positions. Nonetheless, Western scholar-ship on Sinitic civilization (China, Korea, and Japan) has long been dominated by teleologies that assume social and histori-cal change arises from commercial activities and is inherently progressive. Both Marxists and Weberians share this bias. While Marxists refer to the “sprouts of capitalism” in a feudal society [Ji, 2003. p. 73], Weberians seek out “cultural impediments to overseas innovations” [Aiken and Lu, 1998, p. 221].

The Western, economic-determinist approach to account-ing has resulted in by-passing the larger body of accounting practices common to non-profit cooperative societies. The very strengths of the traditional Confucian societies have long been portrayed as impediments. For example, Auyeung [2002, p. 14] lists the Chinese obstructions to the rapid adoption of Western accounting techniques as “centralized political power, a society resistant to change, an anti-merchant mentality and narrow-based learning.” “Rational” is a term reserved for Protestant societies [Auyeung and Ivory, 2003, p. 19]. The assumption is, all choices are equal; the mystery is, why did Confucian societies fail to make the rational choice and emulate Europe? The irony is, Japan and even Europe in the 19th century were in the throes of transforming feudal chaos into functioning structures that would offer stability and the power to mobilize resources and labor. Developments such as centralized governments, societies able to manage change and produce stability, standardized education, and sufficient state power to control and tax merchants had already taken place in China and Korea. By casting Sinitic tradition in a negative light for not having moved a socially despised fringe ethic to center stage, the West has been blinded to the actual rationality at work directed to solving immediate needs. Here we reference “moral economy” to introduce the dominant ethic as a rational response to circumstances and to strip away the negative images favored by Western academics for more than a century. In our concluding remarks, we will return to the main components of this moral economy to interpret the activities revealed in the MCA books and to explain why the profit motive was missing.

A WORKING DEFINITION OF DOUBLE-ENTRY ACCOUNTING

One task of this paper is to determine whether the books of the MCA were kept in a double-entry fashion or something closely approximating it. For this, we will need to have a working definition of double-entry accounting as a guide. The following notes do not presume to offer an exhaustive definition, but do identify a few principles from more well-known historical studies on the development of European accounting practices.

De Roover [1956, p. 114] specified certain minimum re-quirements for an accounting system to qualify as double entry:

… there is no double-entry bookkeeping without the observance of certain strict rules. A necessary prerequisite is that all transactions be recorded twice, once on the debit and once on the credit side. If this requirement is not fulfilled, there is, by definition, no double entry. The principle also involves the existence of an integrated system of accounts, both real and nominal, so that the books will balance in the end, record changes in the owner’s equity and permit the determination of profit or loss.

In addition to a ledger that records entries twice, there must be ledgers for real and nominal accounts, a demonstration of balance, and the possibility of determining profit or loss. In striking a balance, there should be no surplus or loss since this would indicate a simple deduction of liabilities from assets [de Roover, 1956, p. 128]. Other evidence is also desirable – day books and journals that post entries to a ledger, some tracing of accounts for expenses (or transaction costs), a capital account, and a balance sheet [de Roover, 1956, pp. 125, 132, 141].

To be called double-entry bookkeeping, Yamey prefers to see a consistent entry for each transaction in two different places, a capital account, and a profit-or-loss account [Littleton and Yamey, 1956, pp. 6-8; Yamey, 1975, p. 722]. More recently, Yamey seems willing to reduce his requirement to dual entry and now agrees with Lane, who wrote, “as a practical matter, in research, [the student] may regard any accounts with duality of entry as being an elementary form of double-entry” [Lane, 1977, p. 187; Yamey, 1992, p. 706]. Recording transactions in two different places allows balancing, and if the balances of various sub-accounts are fed into a general ledger, a capital account and a profit-or-loss account can be easily drawn up. The use of accounting periods and a single monetary unit might be added to these requirements [Nobes, 1994. p. 246].

We will demonstrate that the accounts for the MCA recorded every entry that crossed ledgers in two different places (although not every transaction within ledgers). There was in evidence an integrated system of accounts (although all accounts were real accounts), accounting for expenses (transaction and wastage costs), denned accounting periods (the agricultural cycle), and balanced books. We will discuss personification (independent accounts trading back and forth and independently recording their trades) as the principle underlying and unifying the MCA accounts. The absence of nominal accounts and profit-or-loss statements will be explained by invoking the societal ethics of the moral economy, the context in which these accounts were produced. Before examining the accounts, we will briefly introduce the provenance of our sources.

VILLAGE AND CLAN ASSOCIATIONS

While commercial establishments were rare, mutual assist-ance associations (kye) were common in late Choson Korea (1598-1910). Individual investors pooled resources and then appointed stewards (yusa) to carry out their aims. The associations usually had three objectives. The first was to act in the public interest, to provide funds for public works, education, and the relief of the poor. The second aim was insurance and mutual aid, providing for marriage costs (honin-kye), funeral costs (sang-kye), and sacrificial rites (chesa-kye). The third aim was investment financing, providing for tree planting (song-kye), irrigation (po-kye), and for the lease of oxen and ploughs (nong’u-kye) [Shi-kata, 1976, p. 71].8 The MCA engaged in all these activities and more.

BOOKKEEPING PRACTICES OF THE MUN CLAN

The account books or yonghagi are among the most impor-tant archives of the MCA. Six account books covering the peri-od from 1741 to 1927 relating to the main clan association and four account books from 1819 to 1881 concerning a branch clan association are available.9 The form of Vol. 1 (1741-1765) differs from all the later volumes. It began as a simple record, but by the 1760s, it had assumed a complex form that became the pattern for all later volumes. Vols. 2-6 contain elaborate accounts that record receipts and expenses in a basic dual-entry form.

8For a description of an 18th century Chinese financial cooperative scheme, see Reiss et al. [1996].
9Main Clan: Vol. 1 (1741-1765); Vol. 2 (1779-1805); Vol. 3 (1806-1816); Vol. 4 (1843-1849); Vol. 5 (1850-1871); Vol. 6 (1884-1928); Collateral Clan: Vol. 1 (1819-1826); Vol. 2 (1827-1841); Vol. 3 (1845-1863); and Vol. 4 (1864-1881). All of these are photolithographically reproduced in Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon (ed.), 1995.

The increasing sophistication of recording after Vol. 1 was likely caused by the growth in the financial scale of the MCA.

Rural Korea in the 18th century was not highly monetized; thus, money was a complex matter. The first use of copper coins (from 1706) appears in a village association record of major local events (1667-1984) [Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon (ed.), 1955, pp. 217-227]. This record appeared 28 years after the central government had begun in earnest to mint metallic coins (1678). These coins were known as sangp’yong t’ongbo (“ever-normal circulating treasure”). Mention of these coins indicates that metallic currency was quickly adopted in the countryside of southwest Korea in a context where pre-industrial agrarian change was slow. From studies of northern China, Huang [1985, p. 47] suggests that it took at least three generations before “secular” change (e.g., commercialization and handicrafts development) was apparent, but in southwest Korea, it seems to have taken about a generation for coinage to facilitate exchange practices.

Despite the spread of coinage, accounts were never ex-pressed in a single currency. In fact, receipts and expenses were denominated in three currencies – unhulled rice, minted copper-bronze coins, and milled rice. The rice payments can be considered payments in kind, but they were so universal and standardized that they actually served as money. Unhulled and milled rice functioned as “rice money,” consumable and storable specie with a natural loss value. Copper cash was more stable. Introduced widely from 1678, its value generally remained steady until 1866, at which time the government is-sued a multi-denominational coin with a face value one hundred times the old coin. Chinese money was also imported to Korea at the end of the 19th century when, as per Gresham’s law, the older, higher-value coins were withdrawn from circulation. Inflation and chaos resulted and lasted into the 1890s when foreign currencies (Mexican and Japanese) began to circulate with new Korean government issues. Financial and economic stability did not begin to re-appear until 1904 when Japanese policies imposed order [Pak, 1969, pp. 30-91, 116-145; Palais, 1996, pp. 855-876, 924-1001]. Strangely, the MCA accounts during the late 19th and early 20th centuries do not show the introduction of the Japanese yen until early 1928 (at the very end of Vol. 6). Until then, the accounts continue to use the old character for copper cash or yang. The consistency in the unit of currency probably indicates a desire to maintain accounting consistency. Since Japanese currency was imposed shortly after the annexation of Korea in 1910, it evidently took about a generation to adopt the new coinage.

The following subsections discuss five separate bookkeeping concepts and methods related to the clan accounts. These topics will be illustrated with exhibits and tables drawn from the source materials.

Developments in the Mechanics of Bookkeeping: Writing in pre-modern Korea was in the East Asian vertical style, top to bottom and right to left. Not surprisingly, the account books of the MCA were written in this fashion. Account books in double-entry format must have a method to distinguish verbally and visually between debits and credits. Littleton [1956, pp. 232-233] discusses the development of journal nomenclature and form in Europe. European accountants developed technical vocabulary and eventually a visual vocabulary of indentation at least by the middle of the 19th century.10 By the 18th century, the accountants for the MCA were deploying indentation, special terms, and word order as their technical apparatus.

At first, two different types of written characters, ordi-nary and large, were employed to facilitate classification, to-gether with an indentation technique. The large character had two usages, marking years and accounts. In the 1741 accounts, large characters marked the year, rental income, and “remaining” cash or rice on hand (see Exhibit 1). By 1744, the use of large characters had disappeared, and the reporting period had changed from an annual report in the twelfth month to biannual reports in spring and autumn.

The most important distinction was between debits and credits, which came to be indicated by special terms, yu ({I?) and then nae (P3). In the 1741 account (Exhibit 1, indicated by C), we can see yu, which means “remaining [assets].” In Exhibit 1, upper and lower sheets, yu indicates old grain kept in storage. In the following year, yu was disappearing and nae was beginning to appear. Within the decade, nae became the standard term with the clear meaning of “total income or assets from

10 Littleton [1956, p. 233] describes the process as follows: “Practice has passed from one definite stage to another: 1. a time of no journal entries, when the full statement of the transaction was probably entered directly in the two ledger accounts concerned; 2. a period (say 1430 to 1550) with a highly technical form of journal entry preparatory to the record in the ledger; 3. a long interval in which the journal entry expressed more or less fully a complete thought; and 4. the modern period – now quite technical in form again – when the focus is the accurate sorting of accounting units.”

which expenditures” would be deducted. Exhibit 2 shows that nae appears in the 1793 accounts at the end of the second col-umn from the far right in the top of the illustration and again at the end of the third column from the far left (indicated with G). Debits were recorded to the right of nae and credits to the left. This use of the term nae to divide expenditures from assets was not unusual in East Asia. It was used extensively in Japanese (Tsushima) trade ledgers from the Tokugawa period. Hyon’s work [1916, p. 25], explaining the methods of the Kaesong merchants, depicts nae playing the same role.

From as early as the 1740s, the MCA accounts used word order (whether words or numbers came first) to indicate the difference between debits and credits. In Exhibit 2, words begin all debit entries and numbers begin all credit entries. This word order was consistently applied from the mid-1750s. Words followed by numbers indicated a positive entry (income) and numbers followed by words signalled a negative entry (payment). For spring accounts, the debit entries all begin with “balance brought forward (from the previous year)” (chonsu or chon as illustrated in Exhibit 2, indicated by F, first appearance 1745), but autumn debit entries often begin with “remaining” (yu), as in “remaining from the previous accounting period.”

Also, from the mid-1750s, entries for expenditures carried a final character, ha. For example, in Exhibit 2 (indicated by H), after the columns that end in nae, all expenditure entries end in ha, except final entries that express “natural loss” (ch”uk, indicated by E). From 1755, subtotals were marked off at the end of sections by the term isang (Exhibit 2, indicated by J), but the use is inconsistent until the records resume from 1779, following a gap of 14 years.11
Although the terms nae and ha appear early to distinguish debits from credits, we do not find extensive indentation until much later. The technique of indentation was developed by the 19th century in English accounting and indicated a separation between debits and credits [Littleton, 1956, p. 232]. Littleton points out that the custom was to indent credits below debits. In Exhibit 1, we can see some experimentation with indentation, but consistency does not appear until 1785. Exhibit 2 for the 1793 accounts shows an indentation style that remained consistent for the next century or more with debit-entry columns beginning higher on the page than credit-entry columns. In short, by the 1780s, the above techniques produced pages that textually and visually showed the relationships between entries.

Personal Accounts and a Division of Administration: Yamey offers four possibilities for the origins of double-entry bookkeeping (DEB). Perhaps it was the work of a single gifted inventor or a triumph of the mercantile ingenuity of the Renaissance. A third possibility is that DEB was an accidental technical development from simpler forms that evolved through a process of accretion and adaptation. The fourth possibility is that DEB was a response to “new or growing business needs not satisfied by earlier methods of record-keeping” [Littleton and Yamey, 1956, p. 2]. The differences between the 1741 and the 1793 accounts kept by the head clan (taejong-kye) of the Mun Clan indicate that, in this case, techniques grew by a gradual process of accretion and adaptation that employed customary techniques already in use. In the earliest records from 1741, items were already being grouped under appropriate headings, indicating a gestation of accounting methods. By the 1760s, accounts had been separated into their own ledgers.

The books kept between 1819 and 1883 by a branch Mun Clan (sojong-kye) show no evolution and display the same so-phisticated form perfected by 1793 in the head clan accounts. However, the branch clan accounts display different emphases from those of the head clan. The head and branch clan books show a division of administration. In particular, the branch clan’s books contain personal accounts. Personal accounts oc-casionally appear in the head clan accounts in connection with memorial rites (filial piety), bad debts, and emergencies, but they exist routinely throughout the branch clan records for fu-nerals and expenditures for seed and tillage. The fact that in-dividual or household names were attached to transactions as well as insurance payments is a significant refinement over the head clan accounts. Table 1 contains an extract from the branch clan accounts and presents the unhulled rice ledger for 1819. Lines 10-19, 22-24, and 33 and 36 are all personal accounts with names indicated in bold.

a) Sogyong is translated here as “annual production cost.” The meaning of the term sogyong is not yet clear. Pak [1999, pp. 54, 313-314] argues that this term refers to taxation, although the usual tax indicators referred to land area (kyol, turak, etc). The Association was not liable for taxation; the tenant was, so we would not expect to see notations for taxation in the Association’s accounts. Based on its appearance continually throughout the accounts for the Mun clan as a credit, the term seems to refer to expenditures for labor (oxen and plowing to prepare the land and lay seed), but may have included a tax subsidy. In the 1741 accounts and in lines 6 and 7 above, we can see sogyong and seed costs as separate items, listed side-by-side, so sogyong was not a seeding cost. This sort of item was quite common in initial payments from the unhulled rice ledger. In lines 13-17 and 22-23, we see pan sogyong, meaning a payment of half of the usual cost of sogyong. Presumably, the tenant was responsible for the remaining half.

These personal accounts link communal and private concerns. The associations kept such elaborate records because they dealt with joint common property, but the personal accounts demonstrate that individual liability was the norm. In-dividual names indicate that the village community was not a faceless collective, a commune; rather, its economic stability re-lied on individual investors and individual responsibility. Goody [1996, p. 7] links individualism and the necessity for accurate accounting.

Individual household responsibility was at the base of production, a fact that becomes apparent when comparing the structure of payments by the head clan (Table 2) with those of the branch clan (Table 3).

Head clan expenditures focus on obtaining copper coins (to purchase specialized items), milling unhulled rice, paying out dividends, and extending funds for ancestral rites, all expenditures that impacted the entire community. Their prominence indicates that the head clan’s overarching concern was for the greater community. Branch clan expenditures were more evenly spread over a variety of local, immediate concerns. There were significant productive payments (seeding and tillage costs within personal accounts), but the largest group of expenditures was for unproductive activities, such as students, education, charity, and public buildings.

The differences between the structure of the head clan ex-penditures and those for the branch clan indicate that the branch clan formed the basic unit of production and supplied most social welfare. The head clan’s function was to manage the external relations that affected all members of the MCA. There was clearly a tiered aspect to the management of the vil-lage economy highlighted by the fact that personal accounts were mostly to be found in the branch clan’s records. The size of the unproductive payments also indicates that surpluses existed which allowed the majority of village members to escape subsistence crises during the 18th and early 19th centuries.

Transaction Costs and Natural Loss: The accounts of the MCA do not contain explicit transaction costs. What we see is the term ch”uk (Exhibits 1 and 2, indicated by E), translated as “natural loss.” We hypothecate that this term indicated the natural loss of grains to vermin and rot (wastage), as well as the transaction costs involved in milling unhulled rice into white rice. Ch”uk was always present in unhulled rice accounts and often present in milled rice accounts, but was not seen in other accounts. Moreover, ch”uk entries were not cross-listed and appeared only as a reduction in stocks. While no cross-listing might support an argument against the designation “double entry,” the presence of these careful entries indicates great concern for the comprehensive and consistent calculation of balance. For example, Exhibit 1 (E: natural loss) records 4 sung as a “natural loss.” The difference between income and outgo was 4 sung, but there is no ex-planation for the deficit, except the term ch”uk, which basical-ly means “shrink” or “shortfall.” Because no rice was milled, we believe that this “shortfall” was a natural loss due to water and rats. From 1765, ch”uk became a regular feature in the accounts.

In the unhulled rice ledger for spring 1793 (Exhibit 2), both “natural loss” (E) and the milling cost of unhulled rice appear (I). Most likely, this natural loss consisted of both real loss and transaction costs. Transactions with rice and the cost of milling almost always went in tandem. Traditionally in rural village markets, there was a toejaeng-i, who measured and milled grain for a commission [Kim, 1977, pp. 299-300]. In the milled rice accounts, there is another natural loss, probably due to rats and water. This loss would not have reflected any further transaction costs after milling, so these costs are most likely due to wastage. With our small sample, we can only catch a glimpse of what might have been the relative size of natural losses and transaction costs. Table 4 presents examples extracted from the accounts for 1741 and 1793-1795.

Natural loss from vermin and rot probably ranged from 0.4 to 0.9%, while transaction costs may be estimated at 3.7 to 4.5%. The high cost for spring 1795 (4.9%) may be attributed to the poor crop of the previous autumn.

An awareness of transaction costs indicates an appreciation for total cost accuracy. Even more minute transaction costs appear as the cost of the paper to record a land sale in the copper cash ledger for 1793 (not shown). Implicit transaction costs appear elsewhere in the form of travel expenses to conduct transactions in distant places or to visit government offices.
TABLE 4 Natural Loss and Transaction Ratios

Ledger ch’uk ($6) ratio Natural loss / Transaction
1741 0.9 per cent Natural loss
1793 spring Unhulled 4.7 per cent Natural loss + Transaction (pure Transaction: 4.3 per cent?)
1793 spring Milled 0.4 per cent Natural loss
1794 spring Unhulled 4.1 per cent Natural loss + Transaction (pure Transaction: 3.7 per cent?)
1795 spring Unhulled 3.2 per cent Natural loss + Transaction (pure Transaction: 2.8 per cent?)

4.9 per centa) Natural loss + Transaction (pure Transaction: 4.5 per cent?)
1795 spring Milled 0.4 per cent Natural loss
a) Includes 9 tu as “lost”. Source: same as Tables 1 and 2.

Transaction costs in Choson Korea were widely recognized. Because rice was an important commodity, even functioning as money, the Choson state had to be able to detect deviations from rules and customs in order to regulate compliance. Many transaction costs involved in creating and maintaining institutions to regulate rice transactions defy our explanation, but it should be noted that the central government was greatly concerned with eliminating non-standard and excessive exactions on the peasantry. To control this abuse, King Sukjong in 1715 established a standard shape that was not the ordinary simple box but a trap-ezoid. An ordinary, wide-mouth box allowed the abuse of “heaping measures,” whereas a trapezoid, with its narrow mouth, wider bottom, and taller body, helped ensure every measure’s exactness and limited “heaping measures” that could be raked off to the official’s private benefit.
Personification or a Simple Division of Accounts?:

The attribution of a living, independent personality to accounts must have had its roots in the very earliest forms of bookkeeping [Jackson, 1956, p. 295].
According to Jackson, the teaching of accounting in Eng-land from the 17th to the late 19th century developed from the rote application of procedural rules to a rational application of judgment based on the concept of personified accounts. Double-entry accounting necessitates the separate establishment of independent accounts (e.g., capital, goods, bills receivable, bills payable, cash, etc.) that swap entries back and forth depending on how one wishes to classify the entry. When a transaction occurs between accounts, it is recorded in both account books as either received (to be in debt to another account or debit) or paid out (to be owed by another account or to be in credit). In other words, by personifying each set of accounts in their separate ledgers, complex accounts could be easily handled and errors detected by comparing the entries and totals in the various ledgers. When all amounts and ledgers are reconciled, the books are balanced. If not, then the accountant or auditor has to search for the error. After surveying pedagogical texts from the early 17th to the late 19th century, Jackson [1956, p. 296] points out that “the practice of explaining the entries to be made in the ledger by means of personifying the accounts is found in
12 King Sukjong issued an order in 1715 to the Board of Taxation that trapezoid measures should be distributed nationally. See Kuksa P’y&nch’an Wiwonhoe (ed.), 1955-1963, Sukjong sillokpogwol chongo 56:1a [1715/02/08 (ulhae)].

the very earliest British texts and must be closely linked with the very origin of the system of bookkeeping.

The MCA account books (yonghagi) may have been an early example of personification. The first volume of the yonghagi runs from 1741 to 1765, and by the spring of 1765, the previous autumn’s unhulled rice remainder was carried down to begin a new integrated account structure with separate ledgers marked off by the term chil (Exhibit 2, indicated by D). Up to the 1760s, however, the use of chil to mark categories was irregular. For example, the ledger for 1741 combined unhulled rice and copper cash accounts, but the copper cash accounts were grouped under a heading (pyol yusa chil) that meant “[items] specially managed by the bursar” (Exhibit 1, indicated by D). Pyol means special; yusa means the bursar for the clan association, a title that is still used today; and chil means order, system, or regularity if read as a Chinese character. When read in a Korean linguistic context, chil was a suffix that indicated something had taken on human characteristics and would act out a certain role. Chil became the standard suffix that marked out an entire and independent ledger, which had to be reconciled with all other ledgers to achieve a balance. In 1741, the separation had not yet occurred. As time passed, specific commodities, particularly milled rice, yeast cakes, and barley, as well as copper cash, were given their own ledgers with debit and credit transactions as if they were living persons.13 Since these items came to be seen as agents themselves, references to the bursar (yusa) disappeared, leaving only the suffix chil. The ledgers, indicated by chil, became stewards, acting on behalf of the owner, and traded assets among themselves and outsiders.

In the spring accounts for 1756, we see the first appearance of the technical term chil to mark off the part of the accounts devoted to copper cash (chon-chil). In 1762, chil is first used to mark off the accounts devoted to milled rice (mi-chil), and it is from this time that a stable personification system that continued until the late 19th or early 20th centuries was in evidence. By the 1793 ledgers, such transactions were extracted from day books and journals and put into their own ledgers, with chil attached as a suffix to identify milled rice, copper cash, barley, and yeast cakes.

13Chil and its use to personify accounts was also described in this way by Hyon [1916, pp. 6, 20] when he reported on the methods reputedly handed down from the 13th century and still in use by Kaesong merchants in the early 20th century.

The special role of the unhulled rice ledger requires clarifi-cation because in Exhibit 2 from the MCA records for 1793 this ledger does not bear the suffix chil, while in other contemporary books it does. Ordinarily the unhulled rice ledger was like any other ledger, but it had a particular status because it contained the main income producing accounts. Unhulled rice was the money that grew from the ground and bought copper cash, yeast cakes, and even barley. Unhulled rice likewise bought or was processed into milled rice to obtain yet a different commodity, an edible commodity, so it is not surprising that the MCA accorded it a special ledger.

In the 1793 example, we can see the full development of independent, personified accounts.14 By 1793, chil had been elevated to act as the title suffix for all ledgers, except unhulled rice. The sequence of ledgers was standardized by the 1760s. In the spring, the ledger sequence was unhulled rice (cho), milled rice (mi-chil), and copper cash (chon-chil). In the autumn, the order was unhulled rice, milled rice, copper cash, barley (mongmaek-chil), and yeast cakes (kokja-chil).

The autumn accounts were closed for the year as indicated by the signatures of the bursar and the auditor attesting to the accuracy of the ledger. The auditor was always someone from outside the MCA, indeed from outside the village, invited to provide objectivity. Independent auditing insured accuracy and transparency; trust was the result.

The foregoing discussion begs the question of whether the ledgers reflected personification or simply a division of accounts. What survives today are separate, independent ledgers, not day books or journals. Transaction entries usually were undated but were not randomly entered. Similar entries were grouped together, indicating that there must have been day books or journals. More importantly, the extant ledgers form a framework of bilateral transactions. Although transactions across ledgers were subject to exchange rates or transaction costs, transactions did occur. These transactions were always recorded twice, once in the issuing ledger (negative) and once in the receiving ledger (positive). Because the various ledgers traded among themselves, it may be concluded that they acted as personified agents and transcended a mere division of accounts.

Nominal Accounts: The MCA ledgers do not include a profit-or-loss ledger (iik-chil). We can conjecture that the MCA knew of such a practice but seemed to have had no need to calculate profit. Hyon’s 1916 primer, based on the traditional practices explained to him by two Kaesong merchants, lists four ledgers necessary to reach a final balance and to determine profit or loss – liabilities (kupch’a-chil), assets (pongch’a-chil), profit (iik-chil), and loss (sobi-chil). The 1916 text clearly outlines a double-entry style with the final calculation of profit or loss in a nominal ledger. The MCA ledgers also contained expenditures, receipts, and losses (transaction costs and natural loss), but no profit ledger. The reasons were probably multiple, but fundamentally derived from the difference between mercantile and agricultural needs. The clan association, insensitive to profit, was sensitive to loss. The MCA was interested in expanding its land holdings, repairing its buildings, entertaining its guests, and providing for its membership. Copper cash was but one of three commodities that could obtain or satisfy these needs. Like modern, nonprofit, cooperative societies, the only concerns of the association were to meet the needs of the membership and to prevent losses. The MCA had no need of a purely nominal, profit ledger; all the MCA ledgers were real accounts with no separate nominal accounts.

The Bookkeeping System: Linked Single-Entry in a Double-Entry Framework: Until now, aspects of the bookkeeping in the clan accounts exhibited certain characteristics that approximated double-entry accounting – certain mechanical innovations (vo cabulary and appearance) that separated debit and credit entries, the presence of personal accounts, the recognition of transaction costs and natural loss, and the personification of accounts. Ultimately, however, all of these features are merely aspects of form. It is now necessary to explain the accounting periods used and the overall integration of the accounts.
From 1741 to 1744, the MCA’s accounting period was one full year. From 1744, the accounts broke the year (lunar twelfth month to lunar twelfth month) in half. The first half (“spring”) opened the fiscal year and extended to the harvest, roughly be-tween the sixth to eighth months. The second half (“autumn”) stretched from the harvest to the closing of the fiscal year in the spring, thus creating two accounting periods. The development of two accounts periods in a single year necessitated the innovation of a special term to indicate “balance brought forward.” Our example (Exhibit 2) of accounts for the spring of the year 1793 starts with the term chonsu (Exhibit 2, indicated by F), which literally means the “unhulled rice balance brought forward from the last account to open the new account.” This term designated the starting balance and brought forward the closing entry obtained from the previous ledger cycle.

The ledgers possessed elaborate technical aspects as all cross-ledger transactions were recorded twice. All ledgers were records of real accounts, with expenditures from them simply deducted from their own capitalization values. Thus, the accounts were not double entry; in fact, they have every appearance of an elaborate set of single-entry accounts linked together to allow cross-referencing and balancing. However, an elaborate single-entry system can closely resemble a double-entry system. Aiken and Lu [1998, p. 230] describe the Chinese Three Feet bookkeeping system as “intermediate” between single and double entry. They point out that this method used double entry for non-silver transactions in which commodities were first converted to silver that was subsequently spent. The silver was recorded twice, once as a receipt from a commodity conversion and once as a disbursement for an expenditure. The MCA accounts are filled with similar examples.

Although the MCA accounts may have been somewhere between single entry and double entry, there was a keen concern with accuracy. One great advantage of double entry is the identification of error. The fact that corrections of errors can be found in the MCA books demonstrates that they were meticulously recorded. Since errors in pre-modern and modern account books in Western Europe are common,15 their presence here is not unusual, but, compared to other contemporary books, surprisingly few errors have been found in the MCA ledgers. The errors that did appear were often related to outstanding rent or grains borrowed; only occasionally were mistakes made in recording. When a mistake was discovered, notes were added around the entry in the ledger to indicate that it was an error and to explain the ramifications of the error on other ledgers. Such entries demonstrate that the ledgers were not just a list of payments, but rather the pinnacle of an elaborate set of integrated day books and journals. In short, what the records represent is an equity account ledger. Table 5 shows that the incidence of er-ror between 1781 and 1808 for the conversion of rice to cop-per cash was 2.7%. Between 1846 and 1882, the nearby Haenam
15″. . . medieval [European] balance sheets do not always balance, because the bookkeeper was either unsuccessful or neglectful in tracing and correcting small differences” [de Roover, 1956, pp. 114-115].

Yun Clan books produced an error rate of 12%, indicating that the Mun Clan was more meticulous in its bookkeeping [Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon, no publication date].

TABLE 5
Error in the Mun Head Clan Account Books for the Period
1781-1808

line year season tu (a)/ total correctly calculated actual record error
decimal yang for 1 sok (per sok or (e = c – d)
sok (b) (c = total yang/ per 20 tu)
decimal sok
1 1781 spring 820.00/ 67.65 1.65 1.65 0.00
41 sok
2 1781 autumn 63.20/ 6.00 1.90 1.90 0.00
3.16 sok
8 1783 spring 66.00/ 10.70 3.24 a)
3.3 sok
22 1786 autumn 26.00/ 4.60 3.54 b)
1.3 sok
50 1793 spring 319.20/ 58.10 3.64 3.70 0.06
15.96 sok
57 1796 spring 96.00/ 11.52 2.40 b)
4.8 sok
58 1796 spring 85.00/ 11.70 2.75 2.70 0.05
4.25 sok
98 1808 spring 345.00/ 29.32 1.70 1.70 0.00
17.25 sok
99 1808 spring 180.00/ 15.30 1.70 1.70 0.00
9 sok
100 1808 spring 320.00/ 28.80 1.80 1.80 0.00
16 sok
101 1808 autumn 300.00/ 25.50 1.70 1.70 0.00
15 sok
Error rate = 2.7 per cent (2/73 ) [1781-1808]
the number of errors = 2, the number of total records of ‘per market price’ = 73
a) “per market price” is hard to discern due to corruption of the document
b) no marking of per market price

Source: see text.

The MCA accounts were linked together. Since all trans-actions were not entered twice, the system was not perfect double entry, but because all cross-ledger transactions were re-corded twice, the fundamental principle of dual entry for the purpose of cross-referencing was clearly in evidence. Dual entries allow the easy tracking of assets and ease the preparation of trial balances. The fact that errors were found, corrected, and referred back to other books testifies to the complexity and accuracy of the system. We must keep in mind that these were the accounts of an agricultural cooperative, an organization that produced and traded in commodities. If the organization had more complicated assets or if the volume of transactions had been greater, then the accounts might well have developed into a fullblown, double-entry system with nominal accounts. Although we do not yet have mercantile books from before the 1850s, we can see a traditional, dual-entry, indigenous Korean accounting system at work in the books of clan associations from the mid-18th century.

CONCLUSION: THE MAXIMIZATION OF UTILITY IN A MORAL ECONOMY

Our discussion of the MCA accounts raises two points. First, the fact that the accounts were kept by a clan association acting as an agricultural cooperative demonstrates that there was no necessary relationship between sophisticated accounting techniques and commercialism. Efficient bookkeeping was undoubtedly conducive to commercial success, but it was also a useful practice within the Korean moral economy. It was a technology that was applied in both contexts precisely because it was rational and efficient.

Second, the primary purpose of the MCA was mutual support, not profit. This would explain the absence of an integrated profit-or-loss balance. The goal was guaranteed subsistence for all members of the association, and the management of an asset pool that would function to maintain a stable community. If everyone had sufficient food, if there was sufficient surplus for communal needs, and if the surplus could stretch to the expression of social ideals (in particular, the ideal of filial piety), then social stability was achievable. Significant expenditures were made for projects best understood as “for the common good.”16 Loans and expenditures that might be called a form of social welfare, even a redistribution of wealth, were extended in hopes

16For example, expenditures for spring sacrifices (Exhibit 1, lower sheet, col-umn 4 from right), a house for the grave keeper and irrigation repairs (Exhibit 2, upper sheet, columns 7-9 from right), sacrifices to the mountain god (Exhibit 2, lower sheet, column 16 from right); Table 1, spring 1819: unhulled rice, lines 3, 4 and 9, 28, 31, 34, 35, 39, and the categories of “land accounts,” “dividends,” and “labor for irrigation repairs” in Tables 2 and 3.

of enhancing communal survival and reciprocity.17 Confucian ideology in 18th century Korea rested on personal responsibility but decried personal profit and enshrined community. We find plentiful evidence in these ledgers of extensive economic commitment to this ideal.

In the MCA accounts, there were numerous expenditures for ceremonies that directly related to the dominant social ideology of filial piety as a key pillar of social stability.18 The performance of filial duties satisfied three needs. First, there was the need for personal emotional expression towards forebears. Second, the education of the young in the principle would eventually instill the responsibility for providing social welfare for the elderly, even the dead. Filial piety was the inter-generational social contract. Third, a filial son would attract community approval as a trustworthy and upstanding member of society. Offer [1997, pp. 450-452] reminds us that Adam Smith stated the purpose of economic activity: ” . . . to be observed, to be attended to, to be taken notice of with sympathy, complacency, and approbation.” The pursuit of wealth beyond survival was the “pursuit of regard.” “The intrinsic benefits of social and personal interaction” or “the satisfactions of regard” are a human propensity perhaps stron-ger than the propensity to “truck, barter, and exchange.” Material welfare, then, was not the sum total of human desire.

The 18th century Korean moral economy put little value on speculation and strove for a surplus that could be used to benefit community solidarity through public displays of communal ideals.19 Lest we risk a descent into romanticism, let us recall that a key element of community solidarity in the southern rice bowl was the maintenance of irrigation facilities.20 Since the members of the association were consumers as well as producers, their ethics were radically different from those of commercial concerns. They were risk-averse in their pursuit of subsistence and concerned with community rather than personal
17For example, expenditures for general distribution (dividends? Exhibit 2, upper sheet, column 11 from left), support of needy dependents (Exhibit 2, upper sheet, columns 1 and 2 from left and lower sheet, columns 1 and 4 from right); Table 1, spring 1819: unhulled rice, lines 10-19, 22-24, and the category of “students, education, charity, public buildings” in Tables 2 and 3.

18For example, expenditures for ancestral memorial rites (Exhibit 2, upper sheet, columns 10-19 from right, and lower sheet, columns 5-15 and 17-28 from right).
19Speculation would appear in the wider society in the 19th century, but that is another story related to the collapse of the social contract [Jun and Lewis, 2005].
20For example, Exhibit 2, upper sheet, columns 8-9 from right.

surplus. In the words of Scott [1976, p. 4], “the peasant household has little scope for the profit maximization calculus of traditional neoclassical economics. Typically, the peasant cultivator seeks to avoid the failure that will ruin him rather than attempting a big, but risky, killing.

To generate subsistence and then surplus required sophis-ticated technologies to monitor community assets. Without ef-ficient and honest oversight, accounts became corrupted, the social fabric frayed, and the membership, including the accountants, ran the risk of starvation. Therefore, incoming and outgoing goods and money were strictly and rationally audited according to rules determined at the general meetings of the association. The communal value put on honest bookkeeping can be seen in the observance of similar customs in widely differing communities. Certain colleges at Oxford and Cambridge brewed a special “audit ale” to be consumed on the day accounts were audited and merchant accounts settled. Regardless of the effect on accuracy and efficiency, the purpose of the custom was to celebrate a shared, communal economy. A similar custom was practiced on auditing day in Chang” am village when wine was ritually served. The Chang”am Village Association and the MCA had an equivalent to audit ale called chonyosi-chu (“audit wine”), known to us because it was carefully recorded as an ex-penditure.

REFERENCES

Aiken, M. and Lu, W. (1993), “Chinese Government Accounting: Historical Per-spective and Current Practice,” British Accounting Review, Vol. 25, No. 2: 109-129.
Aiken, M. and Lu, W. (1998), “The Evolution of Bookkeeping in China: Integrating Historical Trends with Western Influence,” Abacus, Vol. 35, No. 2: 220-242.
Auyeung, P. (2002), “A Comparative Study of Accounting Adaptation: China and Japan during the Nineteenth Century,” Accounting Historians Journal, Vol. 29, No. 2: 1-30.
Auyeung, P. and Ivory, P. (2003), “A Weberian Model Applied to the Study of Ac-counting Stagnation in Late Qing China,” Accounting, Business & Financial History, Vol. 13, No. 1: 5-26.
Bloom, R. and Solotko, J. (2003), “The Foundation of Confucianism in Chinese and Japanese Accounting,” Accounting, Business & Financial History, Vol. 13, No. 1: 27- 40.
Braudel, F. (1983), Civilization and Capitalism 15th-18th Century: The Wheels of Commerce, Vol. 2 (London: Book Club Associates).
Chen, S. (1998), “The Rise and Fall of Debit-Credit Bookkeeping in China: History and Analysis,” Accounting Historians Journal, Vol. 25, No. 1: 73-92.
Cho, I. (2000), Sagae Songdo ch”ibubdp chbnsa – uri nara koyubuji ui paljach”wi (The Pre-History of the Four-Sided Ledger Method of Kaesong City: Traces of Korea’s Characteristic Accounting) (Seoul: Toso ch’ulpan Haenam).
de Roover, R. (1956), “The Development of Accounting Prior to Luca Pacioli, Ac-cording to the Account-Books of Medieval Merchants,” in Littleton, A. and Yamey, B. (eds.), Studies in the History of Accounting (London: Sweet and Maxwell): 114-174.
Gao, S. and Handley-Schachler, M. (2003), “The Influences of Confucianism, Feng Shui and Buddhism in Chinese Accounting History,” Accounting, Business & Financial History, Vol. 13, No. 1: 41-68.
Gardella, R. (1992), “Squaring Accounts: Commercial Bookkeeping Methods and Capitalist Rationalism in Late Qing and Republican China,” Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 51, No. 2: 317-339.
Goody, J. (1996), The East in the West (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon (Academy of Korean Studies) (ed.) (1995), Komunsb chipsong (Collection of Archival Documents, Vol. 21) (Songnam: Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon).
Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon (Academy of Korean Studies) (ed.) (1995), Komunsb chipsong (Collection of Archival Documents, Vol. 22) (Songnam: Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon).
Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon (Academy of Korean Studies) (ed.) (no publication date), Haenam Yun-ssi komunsb (Archival Documents for the Haenam Yun Clan), library microfilm no. 35-003212 and no. 35-003213.
Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon (Academy of Korean Studies) (ed.) (2000), Komunsb chipsong (Collection of Archival Documents, Vol. 51) (Songnam: Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yonguwon).
Hong, H. (1962), “Songdo 4-gae munso e pan’yong toen songsang tul ui toga hwaldong (The Urban Trading Activities of Kaesong Merchants as Reflected in the Four-Sided Kaesong Ledgers),” Ybksa kwahak, No. 6: 50-63.
Hopwood, A. (1987), “The Archaeology of Accounting Systems,” Accounting, Or-ganizations and Society, Vol. 12, No. 3: 207-234.
Hopwood, A. and Miller, P. (eds.) (1994), Accounting as Social and Institutional Practice (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Hsu, T. (1991), “Traditional Chinese Bookkeeping Methodology,” Chinese Busi-ness History, Vol. 2, No. 1: 1-2.
Huang, P. (1985), The Peasant Economy and Social Change in North China (Stan-ford: Stanford University Press).
Huh, J. (1979), “The Traditional Accounting System in the Orient Countries -Korea, China, Japan,” The Academy of Accounting Historians Working Paper Series, No. 22, working paper.
Hyon, P. (1916), Silyong chasu: sagae Songdo ch”ibubbb (Practical Self-Culti-vation: The Four-sided Ledger Method of Kaesong City) (Seoul: Tokhung sorim).
Jackson, J. (1956), “The History of Methods of Exposition of Double-Entry Book-keeping in England,” in Littleton, A. and Yamey, B. (eds.) (1956), Studies in the History of Accounting (London: Sweet and Maxwell): 288-312.
Ji, X. (2003), “Concepts of Cost and Profit in Chinese Agricultural Treatises: with Special Reference to Shengshi Nongshu and Pu Nongshu in the Seventeenth Century,” Accounting, Business & Financial History, Vol. 13, No. 1: 69-81.
Jun, S. and Lewis, J. (2005), “Why did Korea Fail to Modernize? Views from Economic and Environmental Histories,” working paper, Wolfson College, Oxford.
Jun, S. and Lewis, J. (2006), “Wages, Rents, and Interest Rates in Southern Korea, 1700 -1900,” Research in Economic History, forthcoming, Vol. 24.
Kang, M. (1978), “Merchants of Kaesong,” in Chun, S. (ed.), Economic Life in Korea (Seoul: International Cultural Foundation): 88-119.
Kim, S. (1977), Han’guk nongch’on sijang ui chedo wa kinung ybn’gu (A Study of the System and Function of Agricultural Village Markets in Korea) (Seoul: Nong’op kyongje yon’guso).
Kuksa P’yonch’an Wiwonhoe (National History Compilation Committee) (ed.) (1955-1963), Sukjong sillok pogwdl chongo (Veritable Records of King Suk-jong, amended) (Seoul: Kuksa P’yonch’an Wiwonhoe).
Lane, F. (1977), “Doubles [sic] Entry Bookkeeping and Resident Merchants,” Journal of European Economic History, Vol. 6, No. 1: 177-191.
Lin, Z. (1992), “Chinese Double-Entry Bookkeeping before the Nineteenth Cen-tury,” Accounting Historians Journal, Vol. 19, No. 2: 103-122.
Lin, Z. (2003), “Chinese Bookkeeping Systems: A Study of Accounting Adaptation and Change,” Accounting, Business & Financial History, Vol. 13, No. 1: 83-98.
Littleton, A. (1956), “Evolution of the Journal Entry,” in Littleton, A. and Yamey, B. (eds.) (1956), Studies in the History of Accounting (London: Sweet and Maxwell): 223- 235.
Littleton, A. and Yamey, B. (eds.) (1956), Studies in the History of Accounting (London: Sweet & Maxwell).
Loft, A. (1986), “Towards a Critical Understanding of Accounting: The Case of Cost Accounting in the U.K., 1914-1925,” Accounting, Organizations and So-ciety, Vol. 11, No. 2: 137-169.
McKinnon, J. (1994), “The Historical and Social Context of the Introduction of Double Entry Bookkeeping to Japan,” Accounting, Business & Financial His-tory, Vol. 4, No. 1: 181-201.
Nishikawa, K. (1956), “The Early History of Double-Entry Bookkeeping in Japan,” in Littleton, A. and Yamey, B. (eds.) (1956), Studies in the History of Accounting (London: Sweet and Maxwell): 380-387.
Nishikawa, K. (1977), “The Introduction of Western Bookkeeping into Japan,” Accounting Historians Journal, Vol. 4, No. 1: 25-36.
Nisikawa, N. (1994). “The Accounting Inheritance of the Tokugawa Period,” in Yuzawa, T. (ed.), Japanese Business Success: The Evolution of a Strategy (London: Routledge): 191-201.
Nobes, C. (1994), “The Gallerani Account Book of 1305-8,” in Parker, R. and Yamey, B. (eds.), Accounting History: Some British Contributions (Oxford: Clarendon Press): 239-249.
North, D. (1977), “Markets and Other Allocation Systems in History: The Chal-lenge of Karl Polanyi,” Journal of European Economic History, Vol. 6, No. 3: 703-716.
Offer, A. (1997), “Between the Gift and the Market: The Economy of Regard,” Economic History Review, Vol. 50, No. 3: 450-476.
Pak, H. (ed.) (1969), Chungbo Han’guk Hwapyesa (The History of Korean Money) (Seoul: Bank of Korea).
Pak, Pyongho. (1999), “Konae wa sosong ui munso saenghwal (Outgoing-incoming and Litigation Documents),” in Chong, Kubok; Pak, Pyongho; Yi, Haejun; Yi, Yonghun; and Kim, Hyonyong (eds.), Honam chibang komunso kich’o yon’gu (Basic Studies of Documents from the Honam Area) (Songnam: Han’guk Chongsin Munhwa Yon’guwon): 45-130.
Palais, J. (1996), Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions: Yu Hybngwon and the Late Chosbn Dynasty (Seattle: University of Washington Press).
Parker, R. and Yamey, B. (eds.) (1994), Accounting History: Some British Contri-butions (Oxford: Clarendon Press).
Polyani, K. (1944), The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time (New York: Beacon Press).
Popkin, S. (1979), The Rational Peasant: The Political Economy of Rural Society in Vietnam (Berkeley: University of California Press).
Reiss, J., Scorgie, M., and Rowe, J. (1996), “An Historical Example of Discounting in an Early 18th-Century Chinese Financial Scheme,” Accounting, Business & Financial History, Vol. 6, No. 2: 203-211.
Scott, J. (1976), The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asia (New Haven: Yale University Press).
Shikata, H. (1976), Chosen shakai keizaishi kenkyu, (A Study of the Social Econ-omy of Korea), Vol. 3 (Tokyo: Kokusho kankokai).
Someya, K. (1996), Japanese Accounting: A Historical Approach (Oxford: Claren-don Press).
Spengler, O. (1928), The Decline of the West: Perspectives of World History, Vol. II (New York: Alfred A. Knopf), 1980 reprint.
Tanaka, I. (1986), “Shindai Setsuto sozoku no soshiki keitai ni okeru soshi engeki no kino ni tsuite (A Study on the Function of Ritual Drama in Reconstructing Family Relationships in Eastern Zhejiang Province During the Qing Period),” Toyoshi kenkyu, Vol. 44, No. 4: 47-53.
Thompson, E. (1993), “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth Century,” in Thompson, E. (ed.), Customs in Common: Studies in Traditional Popular Culture (New York: The New Press): 185-258, reprint of 1971 article.
Weber, M. (1927), General Economic History, translation of Wirtschaftsgeschichte (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books), 1981 reprint.
Wittfogel, K. (1957), Oriental Despotism: A Comparative Study of Total Power (New Haven: Yale University Press).
Wolf, E. (1969), Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century (New York: Harper & Row).
Yamey, B. (1975), “Notes on Double-Entry Bookkeeping and Economic Progress,” Journal of European Economic History, Vol. 4, No. 3: 717-723.
Yamey, B. (1992), “Double-Entry Bookkeeping,” in Newman, P., Milgate, M., and Eatwell, J. (eds.) (1992), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money & Finance (London: Macmillan): 917-920.
Yi, Y. (2001), Sagae Songdo chi’bubbp kaego (A General Consideration of the Four-Sided Kaesong Ledger Method) (Pusan: Sejong ch’ulp’ansa).
Yoshida, M. (1988), “Kaiju boki kenkyo no sai-kento (A Reconsideration of Re-search on the Kaesong Ledgers),” Chosenshi kenkyiikai ronbunshu, No. 25:133-156.
Yoshida, M. (1999), “Kobe daigaku shozo ‘Kaijo boki chobo’ no shiryo-teki kachi (The Historical Value of the ‘Kaesong Ledgers’ in the Kobe University Col-lection)” Chosen bunka kenkyu, No. 6: 61-93.
Yun, K. (1977), “The Forerunner of Double Entry Bookkeeping: Four-Element Bookkeeping Method in Korea,” Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities, No. 45: 75-86.
Yun, K. (1978), “Poksik pugi tii son’guja – Han’guk tii sagae Songdo clfibubob (The Forerunner of Double-Entry Bookkeeping: The Korean Four-Sided Ledger Method of Kaesong City),” Kybngsang taehak nonjip, No. 6: 99-109.
Yun, K. (1984), Han’guk hoegyesa ybn’gu (Research in the History of Accounting in Korea) (Seoul: Han’guk yon’guwon).
Zensho, E. (1968), “Kaijo no shonin to shogyo kanshu (Kaesong Merchants and Commercial Customs),” Chosen gakuho, No. 46: 105-124.